Pareto optimal

(adjective)

Describing a situation in which the profit of one party cannot be increased without reducing the profit of another.

Related Terms

  • Nash equilibrium
  • Strategic dominance
  • deadweight loss

Examples of Pareto optimal in the following topics:

  • Introduction to Deadweight Loss

    • Deadweight loss is the decrease in economic efficiency that occurs when a good or service is not priced at its pareto optimal level.
    • Deadweight loss is the decrease in economic efficiency that occurs when a good or service is not priced and produced at its pareto optimal level.
    • In a perfectly competitive market, products are priced at the pareto optimal point.
    • the point on the supply curve where the y-coordinate equals the non-pareto optimal price;
    • the point on the demand curve where the y-coordinate equals the non-pareto optimal price.
  • How Taxes Impact Efficiency: Deadweight Losses

    • In economics, deadweight loss is a loss of economic efficiency that can occur when equilibrium for a good or service is not Pareto optimal.
    • In economics, a deadweight loss (also known as excess burden or allocative inefficiency) is a loss of economic efficiency that can occur when equilibrium for a good or service is not Pareto optimal (resource allocation where it is impossible to make any one individual better off without making at least one individual worse off).
  • Understanding and Finding the Deadweight Loss

    • In economics, deadweight loss is a loss of economic efficiency that occurs when equilibrium for a good or service is not Pareto optimal.
    • In economics, deadweight loss is a loss of economic efficiency that occurs when equilibrium for a good or service is not Pareto optimal.
    • When a good or service is not Pareto optimal, the economic efficiency is not at equilibrium.
  • The Prisoner's Dilemma and Oligopoly

    • This outcome is not Pareto optimal; it is clearly possible to improve the outcomes for both players through cooperation.
    • However, the resulting outcome is not Pareto-optimal.
    • Analyze the prisoner's dilemma using the concepts of strategic dominance, Pareto optimality, and Nash equilibria
  • The Demand Curve and Consumer Surplus

    • The price in this chart is set at the pareto optimal.
    • This area represent the amount of goods consumers would have been willing to purchase at a price higher than the pareto optimal price.
  • Impacts of Price Changes on Consumer Surplus

    • It is important to note that any shift from the good's pareto optimal price will result in a decrease in the total economic surplus.
    • A binding price ceiling is one that is lower than the pareto efficient market price.
    • Explain how shifting a price away from pareto optimal will impact consumer surplus
  • Demand Curve

    • Due to how products are priced in this market, consumer surplus decreases below the pareto optimal levels you would find in a perfectly competitive market, at least in the short run.
  • Voluntary Exchange

    • One of the basic concepts described in Chapter I Introduction was "Pareto Efficiency or Pareto Optimality."
    • To review, remember that a Pareto efficient or optimal solution to the allocation problem exists when all the alternatives that will improve the welfare (utility) of a least one person, without making anyone else "worse off" have be exhausted.
    • This improvement is called a Pareto improvement and the result is said to be Pareto superior to the initial alternative.
  • Criteria to evaluate alternatives

    • The optimization (maximization) of technical efficiency can occur by maximizing the outputs for a given input or by minimizing the inputs for a given output.
    • Pareto efficiency is a restrictive criteria and tends to promote the status quo.
    • To remedy this problem the criterion of Pareto Potential is used.
    • The problem with Pareto Potential is that it introduces the question of equity.
    • As societies and individuals change their preferences, technology and environments change and alter the objectives and optimal use of scarce resources.
  • Trade Leads to Gains

    • An allocation of resources is Pareto efficient when it is impossible to make any one individual better off without making at least one individual worse off.
    • Similarly, an action that makes at least one party better off without making any individual worse off is called a Pareto improvement.
    • It is commonly assumed that outcomes that are not Pareto efficient are to be avoided, and if a Pareto improvement is possible it should always be implemented.
    • One way to look at whether a transaction is a Pareto improvement is to ask whether it increases consumer or producer surplus without decreasing either party's surplus.
    • Lowering an item's price without changing the quantity sold, for example, may increase consumer surplus, but is not a Pareto improvement because producers suffer negative consequences.
Subjects
  • Accounting
  • Algebra
  • Art History
  • Biology
  • Business
  • Calculus
  • Chemistry
  • Communications
  • Economics
  • Finance
  • Management
  • Marketing
  • Microbiology
  • Physics
  • Physiology
  • Political Science
  • Psychology
  • Sociology
  • Statistics
  • U.S. History
  • World History
  • Writing

Except where noted, content and user contributions on this site are licensed under CC BY-SA 4.0 with attribution required.